• "How the West Grew Rich, the economic transformation of the industr

    From a425couple@21:1/5 to Peter Jason on Thu Jul 22 20:06:00 2021
    XPost: alt.economics, alt.politics.economics

    On 7/16/2021 3:53 PM, Peter Jason wrote:
    On Thu, 15 Jul 2021 16:07:57 -0700, a425couple
    <a425couple@hotmail.com> wrote:

    On 7/15/2021 2:19 PM, Peter Jason wrote:


    Tariffs?


    Best progress was made when the political sphere
    mostly stuck to the political side of things,
    (good honest deals, fair courts,)
    and let the economic sphere run, let industry and
    commerce serve the general welfare.

    Or, read for yourself,
    Go to Google books, and plonk in -

    it was comparatively out of fashion to regulate trade, tax it appreciably, >>
    hit enter, and it should take you to page viii,
    to read
    "But while it was de rigueur for the political authorities to
    facilitate manufacturing and trade during the main period of
    Western growth, in the nineteenth century it was comparatively
    out of fashion to regulate trade, tax it appreciably,
    control prices ...

    Go up to top of the shown page. Read.

    But, then, It does not show the next page!!!

    Well,,,, the book goes on to say,
    "These advances were accomplished with the help of taxes
    that seem, in retrospect, unbelievably low."


    Well, I remember the USA's Golden Age rode on the back of tariffs. And
    didn't get involved in the Crimean war and similar foolishness!


    ?

    Most sources consider the 1950s to have been the
    USA's Golden age. (Do you? Or do you mean another time?)

    "Has the United States had a golden age?
    It was the Golden Age of the U.S. economy, the quarter century
    between 1948 and 1973, when the U.S. reigned supreme, manufacturing
    flourished and the American middle class prospered. Sep 1, 2017"

    Amazon.com: 1950 to 1959 the USA's Golden Age Begins ...
    https://www.amazon.com › 1950-1959-USAs-Golden-B...
    Amazon.com: 1950 to 1959 the USA's Golden Age Begins: History,
    Book 14 (Audible Audio Edition): Rich Linville, Scotty O'Jay,
    Richard Vaughn Linville: ...

    1950 to 1959 the USA's Golden Age Begins by ... - Audible.com https://www.audible.com › 1950-to-1959-the-USAs-Go...
    May 19, 2021 — Discover 1950 to 1959 the USA's Golden Age Begins as
    it's meant to be heard, narrated by Scotty O'Jay. Free trial available!

    Was the Fifties a Golden Age? | History 118: US History Since ... https://blogs.dickinson.edu › 2015/03/25 › was-the-fifti...
    Mar 25, 2015 — The 1950s certainly marked an era of industrial
    supremacy, big cities, interstate highways, and general stability for
    American capitalism, but ...

    And tariffs were not that important then.
    The income tax was.

    Taxes on the Rich Were Not Much Higher in the 1950s | Tax ... https://taxfoundation.org › taxes-on-the-rich-1950s-not...
    Aug 4, 2017 — Proponents of this view often point to the 1950s,
    when the top ... Average Effective Tax Rate on the Top 1 Percent
    of U.S. Households.

    What are the sources of revenue for the federal government ... https://www.taxpolicycenter.org › briefing-book › what...
    The individual income tax has been the largest single source of
    federal revenue since 1950, amounting to about 50 percent of the
    total and 8.1 percent of ...

    Taxes Weren't More Progressive in the 1950s | The Report ... https://www.usnews.com › opinion › articles › taxes-we...
    Oct 31, 2017 — Second, top marginal rates tell us very little
    about where the locus of the actual tax burden sits across
    all income earners. [. READ: House ...

    U.S. Federal Government Revenues: 1790 to the Present ... https://www.everycrsreport.com › reports
    Sep 25, 2006 — The major source of revenue was customs duties —
    accounting for ... federal revenues varied as a percentage of GDP from
    14% (in 1950) to 21% ...

    includes:
    "Three distinct periods or eras can be identified:
    the customs duties era (before 1863),
    the rising excise tax era (1863-1913),
    and the income tax era (1914-present).
    These periods are identified by the major source of federal revenue.
    Table 1 shows the average percentage of federal revenue coming
    from each of the five revenue
    sources in the three periods. This report describes the sources
    of federal revenues,
    and examines the changing composition of revenues."

    --- SoupGate-Win32 v1.05
    * Origin: fsxNet Usenet Gateway (21:1/5)
  • From gggg gggg@21:1/5 to All on Wed Jul 28 23:22:40 2021
    On Thursday, July 15, 2021 at 1:40:57 PM UTC-7, a425couple wrote:
    Over a month ago, some around here were discussing
    the near famous "Guns, Germs, and Steel" by that
    big shyster Jared Diamond (I find it tough to believe
    that Bill Gates was impressed,,, but "oh well").
    I bought several of Diamond's books. Not impressed!

    I find this below was a wonderful and insightful book.
    I've bought extra copies to give to friends.
    (Currently copies are costing about $5.30 = a bargain)
    Hey - from the Amazon page, go ahead and read some
    in the free "Look Inside" feature.
    Especially the Introduction on page 3 starts giving
    GOOD info.

    "How The West Grew Rich:
    The Economic Transformation Of The Industrial World"
    by Nathan Rosenberg (Author), LE Birdzell Jr. (Author)

    https://www.amazon.com/dp/B001KW02QE/ref=dp-kindle-redirect?_encoding=UTF8&btkr=1

    "How did the West—Europe, Canada, and the United States—escape
    from immemorial poverty into sustained economic growth and
    material well-being when other societies remained trapped in an
    endless cycle of birth, hunger, hardship, and death? In this
    elegant synthesis of economic history, two scholars argue that
    it is the political pluralism and the flexibility of the West’s institutions—not corporate organization and mass production technology—that explain its unparalleled wealth."

    This is Gustafsson's review of How the West Grew Rich

    4.0 out of 5 stars
    Institutions as the fundamental cause, March 21, 2006
    By Fredrik Gustafsson (Lund, Sweden) - See all my reviews

    This review is from: How The West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation
    Of The Industrial World (Paperback)

    Monographs dealing with West's rise from a backward feudal society to
    the most technologically advanced and wealthiest civilization this world
    has ever seen, seem to come a dime a dozen nowadays. Given the large
    amounts of books available on this topic, and the fact that it was
    published twenty years ago, what reasons are there for reading How the
    West Grew Rich? Quite a few I would argue.

    The main question of the book is of course: how, or rather why, did the
    West (as opposed to the South or the East) achieve modern economic
    growth? The authors come to the correct conclusion that standard growth models can only provide the proximate causes of growth. Innovation and accumulation of capital, labour and natural resources is growth, it does
    not explain growth.

    So what, according to R&B, are the fundamental causes of growth? The
    answer lies in favourable institutions and freedom from political restrictions - more specifically, secure property rights and the freedom
    to engage in any line of business and to acquire and sell goods at an unregulated price. This meant that the process of innovation was
    delegated to private firms and that individuals themselves were forced
    to bear full responsibility for their failures and reap the full
    benefits of their successes.

    Why then did such favourable institutions and political and economic freedoms arise in the West? The answer according to R&B is political fragmentation and competition between different territories in Europe. Investments and the merchant class were drawn to areas were property
    rights were respected and where they could carry out their business
    without too much political interference. There was no single empire in Europe. The growth of markets - especially that of cities and
    long-distance trade - further spurred this development.

    The arguments in How the West Grew Rich are, which should be apparent by now, very similar to those found in The Rise of the Western World by
    North and Thomas, although they focus a lot less on population growth.
    As they should, R&B refer to this book on several occasions. Despite
    this fact, How the West Grew Rich proves to be an interesting read: the familiar arguments are explored further and the book includes several interesting examples of how institutional innovations lowered
    transaction costs and facilitated further development.

    There are a number of objections one could raise against R&B's account
    of the rise of the Western world - their account of the middle ages and alternative explanations behind West's success are far from
    satisfactory, to name a few. There are however a few things speaking in favour of this book. First of all, it has a clear message. It does not,
    like some other books on the same topic, name hundreds of different
    reasons for why the West grew rich. Rather, it presents a clear
    hypothesis that is present throughout the book and it also provides very clear policy recommendations to current developing countries wanting to emulate West's success. Secondly, and perhaps because it has such a
    clear message, it is fun to read!

    -------------------------------------------
    The origins of capitalism revealed!, December 20, 2000
    By
    Chad M. Brick (Japan) - See all my reviews
    This review is from: How The West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation
    Of The Industrial World (Paperback)
    "How the West Grew Rich" is a thorough treatise on the rise of
    capitilism in the nation-states of the west, from feudal society towards modern times. Rosenthal and Birdzell discuss in the appearances of the requirements for capitilism, such as acknowledgment of property rights
    and consistent and predictable law. Also discussed are the political, social, or economic changes that caused feudal society to crumble and a variety of free markets to gradually take root and then blossom in Europe.

    This book was thorough and informative, though a bit repetitive and
    somewhat dry. It makes a wonderful companion to Diamond's "Guns, Germs,
    and Steel", filling in where the later left off. -----------------------------------

    "adaptation takes place through the formation of enterprises that are,
    at least initially, small," ie., decentralization=growth., December 26, 2006 By
    komyathy (U.S.A. & elsewhere traveling) - See all my reviews

    This review is from: How The West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation
    Of The Industrial World (Paperback)
    It is entirely safe to generalize: innovation is more likely to occur in
    a society that is open to the formation of new enterprises than in a
    society that relies on its existing organizations for innovation."
    Feudalism thus had to be eclipsed for serious change to occur since it
    "was a society which dealt with the risks of life by legislating rigidity.

    Economic growth is inherently a byproduct of change,

    and the political and religious ideology of the Middle Ages guarded
    against the heresies of change in every way it could," argues the
    authors herein as they set out to explain "how the West generated the organizational and technological skills required to produce and exploit"
    its wealth. A "decentralization of authority," thus was crucial...and
    this was greatly spurred by the Protestant Reformation, the long term
    effect of which, economically,

    "was the progressive removal of religion from intimate involvement in
    the sphere of business activity."

    "In the course of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries , the business sphere was, in a word, secularized." "Protestantism sanctioned a high
    degree of individual responsibility for moral conduct and reduced the authority of the clergy." Under these circumstances, it would have been
    too much to expect the Catholic clergy to continue to stress doctrines
    which could only turn prosperous parishioners toward Protestantism." The authors argue moreover that this "was not wholly a question of the theological content of either Catholicism or Protestantism. It was
    partly a question of the competition inherent in the existence of
    several rival religions, which, like the existence of competition
    inherent in the existence of several rival national states, enabled a
    rising merchant class chafing under the restraints of one authority to
    take refuge with another more congenial" as trade & exchange, both
    domestic and foreign, became ever more prevalent in the prevailing
    economy of the day. But how did such a merchant class even gain a
    foothold in the first place since feudalism was already petering out
    during the 15th century, ie., before the Protestant Reformation and the later rise of capitalism. As the authors remark: "the decline of
    feudalism is complete a century before the beginnings of capitalism."

    "For if one thing is clearer than another, it is that the merchant class
    did not get its economic power from the feudal nobility, or by
    displacing or super-ceding the feudal nobility in agricultural or other economic activities. The merchant class gained economic power by
    expanding the trading activities in which it had always engaged." That's
    the key herein, trade and exchange; or rather, the ability of people to
    be able to engage in such. So the authors argument herein is not that democratization shall necessarily lead to an economic boom, but that the reverse is far more likely; that "economic growth was [and remains, I'd
    add] a force for democratization." Marx was thus, the authors assert,
    wrong yet again: Capitalism wasn't a natural stage progressing out of feudalism, and capitalism doesn't inherently lead to monopolistic centralization of wealth; nor can monopolistic control of the economy
    (under the banner of communism or socialism) drive continued economic growth.

    After all, "one must keep in mind that growth implies change and
    adaptation, and that much of the adaptation takes place through the formation of enterprises that are, at least initially, small." Hence the authors' view that "the strength of the tendency to decentralization in Western economies is chronically underestimated."

    You may bemoan the influence of such mega companies as Microsoft, Exxon,
    & Walmart now and worry how much influence they may have in 20 years,
    but such is but a parlor game of sorts. (Look at the once great US
    Steel, or General Motors, or IBM, or any one of a dozen railroad
    companies, and you can see the futility of simple extrapolation.) Such
    high fliers now are not hurting the American economy. Such companies are stimulating it. That's the point, after all, is it not? Not to penalize success, but to focus on "the value of advancing the material welfare of human beings as measured by the means available to THE GREAT MAJORITY of individuals to choose and shape the quality of the lives they
    lead"(emphasis added). And as long as the Microsofts and Walmarts of our economy continue to add to the growth of such they shall be secure as entities, but there shall come a time when innovations (think Linux,
    Google, Apple multimedia platforms to come, home grocery delivery and internet shopping---you name it) will seek to dethrone them. To wit, the authors point out that a "seldom praised function of competition in
    economic growth is that it eliminates obsolete forms of economic
    activity." (Contrast this to "the difficulty experienced by the
    political sphere in getting rid of programs that are obsolete or that
    have simply failed.")

    Hence "the real point...essential to understanding why the benefits of Western growth were so widely diffused is that the West's system of
    economic growth offered its largest financial rewards to innovators who improved the life-style not of the wealthy few, but of the less-wealthy many.

    This is a point that bodes ill for 3rd world ever-developing
    disappointments (ie., Russia, Venezuela, slews of countries in
    Africa/The Middle East) who are hopelessly (or so it seems) overly centralized and concerned only with enhancing the riches of the elites
    in such societies. Corrupt self-interested cliques are simply
    instinctively hostile to bottom-up anything. Regarding most African and Middle Eastern states, some would say that the Western economic path "involves a diffusion of power and a degree of individualism which is incompatible with many modes of social life" in such parts of the world,
    but the authors herein suggest that such could have been once said about European peoples, too...until power diffused within such societies to an extent made possible by trade-generated economic growth. Nothing is guaranteed, of course, but as long as power remains centralized in
    backwater states the chance of real sustainable economic growth and seriously better lives for the average citizens of such societies will remain but a hopeful wish. (Interestingly, many European economies have begun to grow rather sluggishly since the European Union has been increasingly taking power back from individual states and localities
    with them.) Thanks for reading my words of review of this worthy book. Cheers

    ------------------

    "...The economic transformation of the industrial world" = Gandhi's "Nine days wonder"?;

    https://news.google.com/search?q=gandhi%20nine%20days%20wonder&hl=en-US&gl=US&ceid=US%3Aen

    --- SoupGate-Win32 v1.05
    * Origin: fsxNet Usenet Gateway (21:1/5)
  • From gggg gggg@21:1/5 to All on Wed Jul 28 23:29:13 2021
    On Thursday, July 15, 2021 at 1:40:57 PM UTC-7, a425couple wrote:
    Over a month ago, some around here were discussing
    the near famous "Guns, Germs, and Steel" by that
    big shyster Jared Diamond (I find it tough to believe
    that Bill Gates was impressed,,, but "oh well").
    I bought several of Diamond's books. Not impressed!

    I find this below was a wonderful and insightful book.
    I've bought extra copies to give to friends.
    (Currently copies are costing about $5.30 = a bargain)
    Hey - from the Amazon page, go ahead and read some
    in the free "Look Inside" feature.
    Especially the Introduction on page 3 starts giving
    GOOD info.

    "How The West Grew Rich:
    The Economic Transformation Of The Industrial World"
    by Nathan Rosenberg (Author), LE Birdzell Jr. (Author)

    https://www.amazon.com/dp/B001KW02QE/ref=dp-kindle-redirect?_encoding=UTF8&btkr=1

    "How did the West—Europe, Canada, and the United States—escape
    from immemorial poverty into sustained economic growth and
    material well-being when other societies remained trapped in an
    endless cycle of birth, hunger, hardship, and death? In this
    elegant synthesis of economic history, two scholars argue that
    it is the political pluralism and the flexibility of the West’s institutions—not corporate organization and mass production technology—that explain its unparalleled wealth."

    This is Gustafsson's review of How the West Grew Rich

    4.0 out of 5 stars
    Institutions as the fundamental cause, March 21, 2006
    By Fredrik Gustafsson (Lund, Sweden) - See all my reviews

    This review is from: How The West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation
    Of The Industrial World (Paperback)

    Monographs dealing with West's rise from a backward feudal society to
    the most technologically advanced and wealthiest civilization this world
    has ever seen, seem to come a dime a dozen nowadays. Given the large
    amounts of books available on this topic, and the fact that it was
    published twenty years ago, what reasons are there for reading How the
    West Grew Rich? Quite a few I would argue.

    The main question of the book is of course: how, or rather why, did the
    West (as opposed to the South or the East) achieve modern economic
    growth? The authors come to the correct conclusion that standard growth models can only provide the proximate causes of growth. Innovation and accumulation of capital, labour and natural resources is growth, it does
    not explain growth.

    So what, according to R&B, are the fundamental causes of growth? The
    answer lies in favourable institutions and freedom from political restrictions - more specifically, secure property rights and the freedom
    to engage in any line of business and to acquire and sell goods at an unregulated price. This meant that the process of innovation was
    delegated to private firms and that individuals themselves were forced
    to bear full responsibility for their failures and reap the full
    benefits of their successes.

    Why then did such favourable institutions and political and economic freedoms arise in the West? The answer according to R&B is political fragmentation and competition between different territories in Europe. Investments and the merchant class were drawn to areas were property
    rights were respected and where they could carry out their business
    without too much political interference. There was no single empire in Europe. The growth of markets - especially that of cities and
    long-distance trade - further spurred this development.

    The arguments in How the West Grew Rich are, which should be apparent by now, very similar to those found in The Rise of the Western World by
    North and Thomas, although they focus a lot less on population growth.
    As they should, R&B refer to this book on several occasions. Despite
    this fact, How the West Grew Rich proves to be an interesting read: the familiar arguments are explored further and the book includes several interesting examples of how institutional innovations lowered
    transaction costs and facilitated further development.

    There are a number of objections one could raise against R&B's account
    of the rise of the Western world - their account of the middle ages and alternative explanations behind West's success are far from
    satisfactory, to name a few. There are however a few things speaking in favour of this book. First of all, it has a clear message. It does not,
    like some other books on the same topic, name hundreds of different
    reasons for why the West grew rich. Rather, it presents a clear
    hypothesis that is present throughout the book and it also provides very clear policy recommendations to current developing countries wanting to emulate West's success. Secondly, and perhaps because it has such a
    clear message, it is fun to read!

    -------------------------------------------
    The origins of capitalism revealed!, December 20, 2000
    By
    Chad M. Brick (Japan) - See all my reviews
    This review is from: How The West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation
    Of The Industrial World (Paperback)
    "How the West Grew Rich" is a thorough treatise on the rise of
    capitilism in the nation-states of the west, from feudal society towards modern times. Rosenthal and Birdzell discuss in the appearances of the requirements for capitilism, such as acknowledgment of property rights
    and consistent and predictable law. Also discussed are the political, social, or economic changes that caused feudal society to crumble and a variety of free markets to gradually take root and then blossom in Europe.

    This book was thorough and informative, though a bit repetitive and
    somewhat dry. It makes a wonderful companion to Diamond's "Guns, Germs,
    and Steel", filling in where the later left off. -----------------------------------

    "adaptation takes place through the formation of enterprises that are,
    at least initially, small," ie., decentralization=growth., December 26, 2006 By
    komyathy (U.S.A. & elsewhere traveling) - See all my reviews

    This review is from: How The West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation
    Of The Industrial World (Paperback)
    It is entirely safe to generalize: innovation is more likely to occur in
    a society that is open to the formation of new enterprises than in a
    society that relies on its existing organizations for innovation."
    Feudalism thus had to be eclipsed for serious change to occur since it
    "was a society which dealt with the risks of life by legislating rigidity.

    Economic growth is inherently a byproduct of change,

    and the political and religious ideology of the Middle Ages guarded
    against the heresies of change in every way it could," argues the
    authors herein as they set out to explain "how the West generated the organizational and technological skills required to produce and exploit"
    its wealth. A "decentralization of authority," thus was crucial...and
    this was greatly spurred by the Protestant Reformation, the long term
    effect of which, economically,

    "was the progressive removal of religion from intimate involvement in
    the sphere of business activity."

    "In the course of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries , the business sphere was, in a word, secularized." "Protestantism sanctioned a high
    degree of individual responsibility for moral conduct and reduced the authority of the clergy." Under these circumstances, it would have been
    too much to expect the Catholic clergy to continue to stress doctrines
    which could only turn prosperous parishioners toward Protestantism." The authors argue moreover that this "was not wholly a question of the theological content of either Catholicism or Protestantism. It was
    partly a question of the competition inherent in the existence of
    several rival religions, which, like the existence of competition
    inherent in the existence of several rival national states, enabled a
    rising merchant class chafing under the restraints of one authority to
    take refuge with another more congenial" as trade & exchange, both
    domestic and foreign, became ever more prevalent in the prevailing
    economy of the day. But how did such a merchant class even gain a
    foothold in the first place since feudalism was already petering out
    during the 15th century, ie., before the Protestant Reformation and the later rise of capitalism. As the authors remark: "the decline of
    feudalism is complete a century before the beginnings of capitalism."

    "For if one thing is clearer than another, it is that the merchant class
    did not get its economic power from the feudal nobility, or by
    displacing or super-ceding the feudal nobility in agricultural or other economic activities. The merchant class gained economic power by
    expanding the trading activities in which it had always engaged." That's
    the key herein, trade and exchange; or rather, the ability of people to
    be able to engage in such. So the authors argument herein is not that democratization shall necessarily lead to an economic boom, but that the reverse is far more likely; that "economic growth was [and remains, I'd
    add] a force for democratization." Marx was thus, the authors assert,
    wrong yet again: Capitalism wasn't a natural stage progressing out of feudalism, and capitalism doesn't inherently lead to monopolistic centralization of wealth; nor can monopolistic control of the economy
    (under the banner of communism or socialism) drive continued economic growth.

    After all, "one must keep in mind that growth implies change and
    adaptation, and that much of the adaptation takes place through the formation of enterprises that are, at least initially, small." Hence the authors' view that "the strength of the tendency to decentralization in Western economies is chronically underestimated."

    You may bemoan the influence of such mega companies as Microsoft, Exxon,
    & Walmart now and worry how much influence they may have in 20 years,
    but such is but a parlor game of sorts. (Look at the once great US
    Steel, or General Motors, or IBM, or any one of a dozen railroad
    companies, and you can see the futility of simple extrapolation.) Such
    high fliers now are not hurting the American economy. Such companies are stimulating it. That's the point, after all, is it not? Not to penalize success, but to focus on "the value of advancing the material welfare of human beings as measured by the means available to THE GREAT MAJORITY of individuals to choose and shape the quality of the lives they
    lead"(emphasis added). And as long as the Microsofts and Walmarts of our economy continue to add to the growth of such they shall be secure as entities, but there shall come a time when innovations (think Linux,
    Google, Apple multimedia platforms to come, home grocery delivery and internet shopping---you name it) will seek to dethrone them. To wit, the authors point out that a "seldom praised function of competition in
    economic growth is that it eliminates obsolete forms of economic
    activity." (Contrast this to "the difficulty experienced by the
    political sphere in getting rid of programs that are obsolete or that
    have simply failed.")

    Hence "the real point...essential to understanding why the benefits of Western growth were so widely diffused is that the West's system of
    economic growth offered its largest financial rewards to innovators who improved the life-style not of the wealthy few, but of the less-wealthy many.

    This is a point that bodes ill for 3rd world ever-developing
    disappointments (ie., Russia, Venezuela, slews of countries in
    Africa/The Middle East) who are hopelessly (or so it seems) overly centralized and concerned only with enhancing the riches of the elites
    in such societies. Corrupt self-interested cliques are simply
    instinctively hostile to bottom-up anything. Regarding most African and Middle Eastern states, some would say that the Western economic path "involves a diffusion of power and a degree of individualism which is incompatible with many modes of social life" in such parts of the world,
    but the authors herein suggest that such could have been once said about European peoples, too...until power diffused within such societies to an extent made possible by trade-generated economic growth. Nothing is guaranteed, of course, but as long as power remains centralized in
    backwater states the chance of real sustainable economic growth and seriously better lives for the average citizens of such societies will remain but a hopeful wish. (Interestingly, many European economies have begun to grow rather sluggishly since the European Union has been increasingly taking power back from individual states and localities
    with them.) Thanks for reading my words of review of this worthy book. Cheers

    ------------------

    "...The economic transformation of the industrial world" = Gandhi's "Nine days wonder"?;

    https://news.google.com/search?q=gandhi%20%22nine%20days%20wonder%22&hl=en-US&gl=US&ceid=US%3Aen

    --- SoupGate-Win32 v1.05
    * Origin: fsxNet Usenet Gateway (21:1/5)